Zephyrnet Logo

Data Lessons in Equity and Public Transportation from the Majority World

Date:

Click to learn more about author Devin de Vries.

Despite constant speculation that new tech is
on the verge of disrupting public transport, getting around town these days
still looks a lot like it did for our grandparents: buses and metro systems for
most, with a sprinkling of bicycles and cars. The Hyperloop and flying cars are
conspicuous only by their absence.

Public transport authorities, fearing impending irrelevance from this promised new tech, have tried their hands at new services. Bikeshare, allowing for some hiccups with dockless clutter and operator abandonment, has mostly been a success, adding a new mode of transport that can work well for low-income populations — typically those for whom public transport is most important.

On the other hand, public transport
authorities’ flirtation with on-demand micro-transit has mostly come to
nothing. The idea behind the on-demand model is to use smaller vehicles than
buses on flexible routes. Passengers can request trips by smartphone, making
for quicker and more convenient trips than the beleaguered, fixed-route city bus
(or so the thinking goes).

This failure comes despite the proliferation
of informal public transport around the world. In most emerging-market cities,
small vehicles on semi-flexible routes make up the backbone of mobility
networks. Vehicles operate profitably without subsidies.

The same on-demand, “informal” service model has been trialed in developed markets, but these well-publicized pilot programs haven’t scaled, and the obstacles were fairly predictable: Unlike informal systems in the developing world, on-demand transport in the developed world is generally expensive and inequitable.

Transport authorities’ highest operating cost by far is wages and benefits (about 60 percent for authorities in the US, as one example). A bus driver’s wage can be shared across many passengers, while smaller vehicles picking people up on-demand simply costs more per passenger. Spending more per passenger could be acceptable if there’s a need to do so (such as in door-to-door services for the disabled). But on-demand pilots generally don’t target passengers based on mobility needs. Some programs run by public transport authorities have inadvertently swung the other way, reaching the relatively well-off by limiting service to those with smartphones. The result is a comparatively luxurious service for a privileged few, rather than improvements to the nuts-and-bolts bus and metro services that make cities run.

Learning
from the Majority World

The Majority World is an alternative term for
developing countries, and the moniker reveals an important truth: Most urban-dwellers live in places that are
very different from London, Paris, or New York.
Most of the world’s
population lives in cities, and most of those — 3.2 billion people — live in
Majority-World cities: places like Rio de Janeiro, Kampala, and Mumbai.

For urbanites in the Majority World, public
transport is mostly informal. Private operators run 12- to 16-seater vans on
semi-flexible routes that criss-cross the city, overlapping and extending the
formal public transport network. Mexico City has more than 1,400 of these
informal routes, compared to roughly 200 formal bus and metro lines.

Informal transport certainly has room for improvement. Routes are unmapped, for example; operators themselves don’t necessarily know all of the thousands of informal lines. The networks remain largely offline, and the lack of publicly available information on the network, with no real-time information at all on vehicle locations, leaves passengers in the dark. These are the problems that my company is solving. In fact, our recent program to be the first company to collect the complete set of vital data on formal and informal public transport in the 30 largest emerging-market cities in the world will transform the public transport experience for hundreds of millions of people. The digitalization of these networks for the first time has begun and is set to be completed by 2023.

In spite of some of the informal transport
issues, informal networks claim one huge advantage: They work. They transport
around 2 billion people every month in the world’s largest low- and
middle-income cities. Developed world cities would do well to learn from what
they do well.

Relaxing regulations on who can operate
vehicles generally makes for strong competition and relatively low fares, even
with no government subsidies. Smaller vehicles keep upfront costs and fuel
bills low, making it economical to reach even low-density suburbs outside the
urban core — the sorts of neighborhoods that are worst-served by formal public
transport.

Public transport along these lines basically
doesn’t exist in Western cities, but it used to. In North America, “jitney vans”
burst onto the scene about a century ago, rapidly gaining market share for
urban transport. A coordinated effort from the tram and taxicab companies to
pass regulations to kill the industry stopped their rise. [1] Yet a few
vestiges of the era remain, notably in New York and Miami, where “dollar vans”
continue to provide cheap rides in small vehicles.

Informal
Transport Can Mean Better Equity

Simply copying models from Nairobi and Dhaka won’t work for New York and London (nor does it work the other way around). Majority-World cities have lower labor costs, as well as denser demand for public transport than wealthier cities. Informal transport networks will not, therefore, take over the mobility market, nor should they.

But for many communities, especially outside city centers, privately run vehicles could be a lifeline (and turn profits for owners and operators). The map of public transport access in Stockholm is typical: Access to fast, frequent public transport is good for those going to jobs in the center city. But access falls precipitously outside the urban core, especially for anyone looking to travel from suburb to suburb. These are precisely the areas with the greatest concentration of low-income residents.

With low-income communities disproportionately relying on public transport, this confluence of factors — high need but low access — limits opportunity.

Access is also lower in smaller cities than
larger ones. In Eindhoven, less than 20 percent of the population has high
access to public transport, compared to over 60 percent in Antwerp.

Loosening restrictions on informal public transport may not yield the sort of high-growth, venture-backed startups we tend to think of as successful businesses these days. Recent attempts at high-end commuter buses have mostly failed (Chariot’s commuter shuttles and Citymapper’s bus service come to mind), in part since they tend to compete with well-developed transport networks in urban centers.

More likely to be profitable are smaller
minibus companies connecting lower-income neighborhoods on cities’ outskirts.
These companies can provide a vital service, connecting communities that have
no formal public transport links. For example, “dollar vans” in the New York
City area often run between communities with large populations of people who
migrated from the same country, but where there are no good formal public
transport connections.

At a time when we profess to strive for equity and inclusion, what’s better than a cost-free reform that allows for community-built solutions that disproportionately benefit low-income people? What do we have to lose from trying? The journey to mapping the largest emerging megacities continues.

References
[1] The
Jitneys / Ross D. Eckert. The Journal of Law & Economics: v.15: no.2, 1972,
p.293

Source: https://www.dataversity.net/data-lessons-in-equity-and-public-transportation-from-the-majority-world/

spot_img

Latest Intelligence

spot_img